Show simple item record

dc.contributor.authorLE QUEMENT, Mark
dc.date.accessioned2009-07-13T08:01:17Z
dc.date.available2009-07-13T08:01:17Z
dc.date.issued2009
dc.identifier.citationFlorence : European University Institute, 2009en
dc.identifier.urihttps://hdl.handle.net/1814/12038
dc.descriptionDefence date: 8 June 2009en
dc.descriptionExamining Board: Marco Celentani, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid; Olivier Gossner, Paris-Jourdan Sciences Economiques; Karl Schlag, Supervisor, Universitat Pompeu Fabra; Fernando Vega-Redondo, European University Instituteen
dc.descriptionPDF of thesis uploaded from the Library digital archive of EUI PhD thesesen
dc.description.abstractThe first chapter examines the performance of a simple forecasting rule within a complex environment and evaluates the cost of operating with a model that only partially embraces the complexity of the faced serially correlated process. The intuition behind the simple forecasting rule examined is the following: when knowingly facing a serially correlated environment, I may simply forecast at every period the most frequent follower of the outcome observed in the preceding period . Thus, when predicting tomorrow’s weather, I may simply predict the most frequent follower of today’s outcome, whether rain or sun. In the case that we study, the process driving observed outcomes however renders such a strategy imperfect. This strategy, indeed, would be optimal only in the case of a first order Markovian process. In contrast, against the process that we study, a forecaster would always benefit from conditioning his choice on longer sequences of events. Instead of asking, "What usually happens after a rainy day?", he would benefit from asking what happens after more complex chains of events such as for example: "What happens after 2 rainy days or after a sequence of 5 rainy days followed by 2 sunny days?". Comparing the performance of our minimalist forecasting rule to that of the best possible forecaster, we demonstrate that in the particular case of a simple hidden Markovian environment, the highest possible foregone revenue from operating with a poor model is quite limited. Chapter 2 and 3 address the issue of learning within a social environment. The crucial characteristic of learning within social environments is that the available information reduces to what other agents are willing or able to reveal. One may think of information as a .uid that permeates systems of agents. In this light, the issue then becomes to understand the mechanics of this fluid: how does it flow between agents, what are the forces impeding its full diffusion within the system? And if diffusion is only local or partial, what are reasonable models of such partial diffusion processes and equilibrium diffusion patterns?en
dc.description.tableofcontents-- Boundedly rational forecasting in Amarkovian environment -- Cheap talk, multiple senders and endogenous consultation -- Subgroup deliberation and votingen
dc.format.mimetypeapplication/pdfen
dc.language.isoenen
dc.publisherEuropean University Instituteen
dc.relation.ispartofseriesEUIen
dc.relation.ispartofseriesECOen
dc.relation.ispartofseriesPhD Thesisen
dc.rightsinfo:eu-repo/semantics/restrictedAccessen
dc.subject.lcshEconomics -- Methodology
dc.subject.lcshCognitive science
dc.titleEssays on communication and learningen
dc.typeThesisen
eui.subscribe.skiptrue


Files associated with this item

Icon

This item appears in the following Collection(s)

Show simple item record